Wednesday, June 5, 2019
Impact of Foreign Aid on Economic Growth
repair of unknown Aid on Economic Growth surchargeThe massive expenditures on impertinent encourage programs by unquestionable nations and international institutions, in combination with the perceived want of terminations from these disbursements, raise important questions as to the actual potentness of monetary assistance to less developed countries (LDCs). In this analysis, I focus on 119 low- and medium-development countries, and measure the collision that opposed stinting guardianship has on their emersion rates of gross domestic product, using dummy variables for geography and counterpoint in a geometric lag toughie.The results indicate that impertinent tending donations do have a positive come to on the economic return of the recipient nation. The effect is extremely modest, however, and other factors such as armed skirmish and geography can easily mitigate this strike, in some pillowcases to the extent that outside(prenominal) back up becomes detri mental to economic growth. Further analysis of the results indicate that this equal is quickly felt, with half of the total shock absorber of impertinent instigate felt in approximately six months.Key Words Foreign abet, economic growth, economic development1. IntroductionOver the last half century, foreign aid has emerged as a dominant system for anyeviating poverty in the third world. non coincidentally, during this meter period major international institutions, such as the linked Nations, World Bank, and International Monetary Fund gained prominence in global economic affairs.1Yet it seems that sixty years later, the lesser developed countries (LDCs) of the world continue to suffer from economic hardship, raising questions of whether foreign aid is a worthwhile and effective approach to boosting growth and development in recipient economies. Research on the subject has travailed to draw an empirical connection between foreign aid and economic growth. Despite these ef forts, however, there is no solid consensus among scholars on the actual effectiveness of foreign aid inflows.2The term foreign aid can signify a number of different activities, ranging from humanitarian support in the wake of natural disasters to military assistance and arms donations.3For the purposes of this analysis, however, I refer to the standard explanation of official development assistance, or aid that is aimed at change magnitude economic development, and has a grant component of at least 25% of the total aid package.4Critics of development assistance cite a variety of reasons why it is a poor strategy for combating global poverty. Some argue that it can breed corruption, relent accountability, and cause government to become excessively large.5Nonetheless, as look intoers Hansen and Tarp (2000) write, it is neither analytically defensible or empirically credible to argue from the outset that aid never works.6Indeed, a number of studies have shown a positive relations hip between foreign aid and economic growth, especially in countries which have trusty economic policies regarding switch over, inflation, and other macroeconomic concerns.The purpose of this analysis is to memorise the do of foreign aid inflows on real gross domestic product growth rates. It differs from existing research in two key ways. First, I go for a geometric lag model to capture the continued rival of foreign aid inflows for years after(prenominal) its initial introduction into the saving.7Second, I incorporate several dummy variables for geography, political stability, and development to understand their additional impact on foreign aids effectiveness in growing gross domestic product.2. Literature ReviewThere atomic number 18 two contrasting sides to this debate one which argues that aid has a positive effect on economic growth, with even more impact in countries with sound economic and trade policies and another which contends that foreign aid causes corrupti on, encourages rent-seeking behavior, and erodes bureaucratic institutions. A renewed interest in explaining cross-country economic growth emerged in the early 1990s, with numerous studies attempting to answer the foreign aid question. To date, however, there is no consensus among scholars as to the actual effects of foreign aid on economic growth.There have been several prominent studies which find a causal get together between foreign aid and economic growth. Perhaps the most well-known of these was performed by two researchers for the World Bank, Craig burnside and David Dollar (1997). They found that foreign aid enhances economic growth, so long as wide fiscal policies are in place. These policies can include maintaining small budget deficits, controlling inflation, and being commit to global trade.8Durbarry, et. al. (1998) in like manner found a positive association between foreign aid and economic growth, and confirmed Burnside and Dollars finding of conditionality on goo d economic policy. The ruminate overly concluded, however, that the degree to which aid impacts GDP depends largely on other factors as well, such as geography.9Ali and Isse (2005) further confirmed the findings of Burnside and Dollar. The study also demonstrated, though, that aid is subject to decreasing marginal returns, indicating a doorstep beyond which development assistance can become detrimental to economic growth.10Not all research has shown a positive relationship to exist between aid and growth. Even before Burnside and Dollars monumental findings, a study by Peter Boone (1994) found that aid-intensive African countries experienced zero per capita economic growth in the 1970s and 80s, despite foreign aid actually increasing (as measured by share of GDP).11Additionally, Knack (2001) found that high levels of foreign aid can erode bureaucratic and institutional quality, triggering corruption, and encouraging rent-seeking behavior.12There is also evidence that the effects of foreign aid can be mitigated by other non-economic factors. Situations of state failure, such as ethnic conflict, race murder or politicide, and revolution can all potentially influence the extent to which aid impacts growth. George Mason Universitys Political dissymmetry Task Force (PITF) created a binary infoset indicating in which countries and during what years these events arrive place. According to the PITF, an ethnic conflict requires the clash of two separate ethnic, religious, or nationalistic factions, and also must meet two threshold criteria 1,000 people must be mobilized for armed conflict, and at least 1,000 people per year must have died as a direct result of this conflict. Similarly, revolutions are defined as episodes of violent conflict between political groups in hopes of overthrowing the current regime, and must meet the same threshold criteria as ethnic wars. Finally, genocide and politicides are defined in a slightly different manner. These events occur when the group in power carries out sustained policies that target ethnic, religious, or political rivals, ultimately resulting in the deaths of a substantial portion of one of those groups.13Easterly and Levine (1997) studied the effects of high ethnic fractionalization on economic growth. By fractionalization, they besotted the probability that two randomly chosen people from a population go forth be of different ethno-linguistic backgrounds. Easterly and Levine conclude that movement from heterogeneity to homogeneousness (decreasing fractionalization) results in better schooling, more efficient infrastructures, and more developed financial systems and foreign exchange markets.14According to their findings, then, it is entirely possible that ethnic conflict, in its attempt to move away from ethnic diversity and towards ethnic homogeneity, will actually improve economic growth. Despite their findings, however, the instability of the regime could still negatively impact the degr ee of aids effectiveness.Not a lot of attention is paid to genocide, politicide, and revolution and their effects on growth in the literature. Moreover, there has been virtually no research performed on this question as it concerns the effectiveness of aid. It is reasonable to believe, though, that resources (including foreign aid) are siphoned off by the dominant party and used for individual welfare rather than for economically efficient activities, as intended.Furthermore, out of respect for state sovereignty, these events are not likely to prompt a major international response, which would maybe eliminate local control over resources and allow them to be used productively. Ethnic conflict, on the other hand, typically ignores state boundaries. One study by Gurr (1993) estimated that over two-thirds of identified ethnic communal groups in the world have kindred in another country. The spread across state borders allows other states to throw in without violating state sovereignt y, which could positively impact how resources are used, and ultimately, economic growth.Additionally, a countrys geographic location can influence economic performance nations that are inland, for instance, are at a natural disadvantage in global trade. Sachs and Warner (1996) write,Landlocked countries, in particular, face very high costs of shipping, since they must pay road send out costs across at least on international boundary in addition to sea freight costs. Although air shipments can help belabor many of these problems, only certain goods can be economically shipped by air, and most countries still import and export the majority of goods by the sea.15A promulgate by the UN Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific (1999) specifically mentions the positive relationship between aid and growth in landlocked countries, noting that they are at a disadvantage for these reasons, as well.16 due(p) to their geographical position, then, landlocked countries could p otentially benefit from foreign assistance, as it may fill the gap in trade that they experience relative to countries with easy access to international trade.3. Methodology3.1 DataI direct the focus of this analysis to low- and medium-development countries as defined by the United Nations instruction Programme (UNDP) in its Human information Index (HDI).17These nations were selected since they are the most likely to be recipients of foreign aid, whereas high-development nations are the most likely to be donors. I select the HDI as a basis for classification because in addition to income, the index accounts for life expectancy as measured by child mortality rates, and educational attainment as measured by adult literacy rates and gross enrollment ratios for primary, secondary, and tertiary schools. This provides for a more thorough ground of a countrys stage of development and a comprehensive measure of quality of life.18In all, 119 countries of the 177 analyzed by the UNDP (67% ) meet the development criteria and were included in this study.19Due to data availability issues, I restrict the range of this study to the period from 1980 to 2003. With 119 cross sections, there is a potential 2,856 observations over this time span. After victorious into account missing data for the independent variables included in the model, 1,760 remain, or about 62%. A vast majority of the missing data is a result of the overall lack of information regarding Sub-Saharan Africa and Soviet bloc countries during the early 1980s. Furthermore, I aim to measure the impact of foreign aid on average, across both time and countries. Thus, I employ pooled data analysis.I collect the data in annual format from several sources. Most of the data come from the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD)20and the International Monetary Fund (IMF).21Table 1 below lists the variables included in this study and the source from which they were gatheredTable 1 Data SourcesVariab leUnitSource plebeian Domestic ProductGrowth RateIMFOfficial Development AssistanceMillions $USUNCTADHousehold ConsumptionGrowth RateUNCTADGovernment ExpendituresGrowth RateUNCTADExports*Petroleum ExporterGrowth RateUNCTADImportsGrowth RateUNCTAD plain ProductionGrowth RateUNCTADGross Capital FormationGrowth RateUNCTADInflationGrowth RateIMFOpenness to Trade22Share of GDPUNCTADEnergy Consumption Per CapitaMillions of BTUsEnergy Information Agency, U.S. Dept of EnergyMajor Petroleum Exporter Dummy1=Yes, 0= otherwiseUNCTADNon-Tropics Dummy231=Yes, 0=OtherwiseIUCN World Conservation UnionForeign Direct Investment InflowsMillions $USUNCTADEthnic Conflict Dummy1=Yes, 0=OtherwisePolitical Instability Task Force, University of MarylandGenocide Dummy1=Yes, 0=OtherwisePolitical Instability Task Force, University of Maryland variety Dummy1=Yes, 0=OtherwisePolitical Instability Task Force, University of MarylandLandlocked Country Dummy1=Yes, 0=OtherwiseUNCTAD first gear Development Dummy1=Yes, 0=OtherwiseUnited Nations Development ProgrammeData for household consumption, government expenditures, exports, imports, agricultural production, and gross capital formation were only available in share of GDP format. Since I aim to explain growth rates in GDP, however, percentage changes in the dollar amounts of each of these variables would be more appropriate. Thus, I transform these numbers into growth rates as well.243.2 Model SpecificationI assume that inflows of foreign aid will continue to impact the economy for years after its initial introduction, but at a decreasing rate. It would therefore be unsuitable to use an ordinary least squares model, since it would only take into account aid inflows in the year they were received and disregard the continued impact that foreign aid has on the economy in the years after its introduction. To effectively capture this rationale, I use a geometric lag model which incorporates an infinite number of lags for each variable, but weights each lag in a geometrically declining fashion. The general form of this type of model is(1)Note that in the model a weight is attached to each lag (), a value between zero and one that diminishes geometrically as time passes. Mathematically, this model is the same as25(2)This simpler form, however, shows the dependent variable Y on the accountability side of the equation. Since Y is already shown to have an error component in (1), this simplification introduces a stochastic regressor into the model, requiring two-stage least squares (TSLS) regression. In order to ensure the instruments ask for TSLS are non-stochastic, I lag each one period. Thus, to the observer at time t, values for instruments at t-1 are fixed. In other words, these instruments are stochastic but predetermined.3.3 Expected ResultsI expect to find a positive relationship between foreign aid and economic growth on average, as indicated by most prior research on this subject. I further anticipate, however, that ai d will have a detrimental effect on low-development countries since they lack efficient infrastructures and institutions which might make foreign aid donations more effective. I expect ethnic conflict, genocide and revolution to negatively influence the effectiveness of foreign aid, but leave open the possibility that ethnic conflict could positively influence aids impact based on Easterlys study. Furthermore, I expect landlocked countries to experience additional positive gains from foreign aid, since they are at a trade disadvantage.4. Results and AnalysisThe results of the TSLS regression are shown below in Table 2Table 2 TSLS Regression ResultsParameterEstimateStd. Errort-StatisticProb.Constant Term0.0910.4000.2280.820GDP(-1) Lambda0.2330.0872.6920.007Household Consumption6.3072.2412.8140.005Government Expenditures4.5051.3053.4520.001Exports*Petroleum Exporter9.8251.8665.2660.000Imports-3.7460.963-3.8910.000Agricultural Production10.9761.9925.5100.000Gross Capital Formation7.262 0.8348.7030.000Inflation-0.0010.000-2.2820.023Openness to Trade0.0200.0054.3010.000Energy Consumption-0.0130.004-3.2120.001Energy Cons.*Low Dev.-0.0520.014-3.8220.000Less than Half of Land in Tropics (1=Yes)0.7420.3262.2750.023Foreign Direct Investment0.0000.0002.1240.034Foreign Aid0.0010.0003.2330.001Foreign Aid*Ethnic Conflict0.0010.0002.2020.028Foreign Aid*Genocide*Low Dev.-0.0170.009-1.9480.052Foreign Aid*Revolution-0.0010.000-2.7310.006Foreign Aid*Landlocked0.0020.0011.8470.065Foreign Aid*Landlocked*Low Dev.-0.0030.001-2.3200.021R-squared0.415S.E. of regression4.535Adjusted R-squared0.408Durbin-Watson stat2.069The model can be written as in general terms as follows(3)WhereGDP = Gross Domestic Product Growth Rate (for country i at time t)ODA = Official Development Assistance (for country i at time t)DUMMY = Vector for Dummy Variables (for country i at time t)Z = Vector for only Other Variables (for country i at time t)The results of the regression indicate that approximately 42 % of the variation in GDP growth rates is explained by the variables included in the model, as evidenced by the R-squared value. Further, each coefficient estimate is significant at the 0.05 level, with the exception of a few borderline cases and the constant term. These coefficients are also consistent with my expectations, however the coefficient for the ethnic conflict dummy did turn out to be in harmony with Easterlys study of ethnic fractionalization.The Durbin-Watson statistic fails to conclusively determine the presence of serial correlation. Further analysis of the residuals, however, indicates that it is not a statistically significant problem.26The model was also tested for the presence of heteroskedasticity, both across time and cross sections using the Breusch-Pagan Test. The results of this test fail to show statistically significant evidence of heteroskedasticity.27Multicollinearity was investigated using a correlation matrix of the regressors, but no major evidence of this anomaly was detected, either.28The results provide insight as to foreign aids effectiveness in a number of ways. Most obvious is that it is has a positive, though modest effect on economic growth, significant at the 0.01 level. Increasing foreign aid by $1 million US will result in an increase in GDP of approximately 0.001%, ceteris paribus. According to the data, the average annual amount of official development assistance received over all years and countries is approximately $570 million US. In this case, aid is estimated to increase growth in GDP by approximately 0.6%.As shown in Table 3, however, this impact can be greatly diminished by other factors, in some cases to the point where aid actually becomes detrimental to growth. Using the baseline case of a country with no ethnic conflict, revolution, or genocide, which is not landlocked, and does not suffer from low development, I estimate the additional impacts of any of those circumstances on economic growth. Those facto rs with N/A listed under Impact were not statistically significant at the 0.05 level.29Table 3 Factors Influencing Aid EffectivenessFactorImpactOverall Impact of Aid + Additional Factor(s) on GDPEthnic Conflict0.0010.002Ethnic Conflict in Low Development CountriesN/AN/AGenocide/PoliticideN/AN/AGenocide/Politicide in Low Development Countries-0.017-0.016Revolution-0.0010.000Revolution in Low Development CountriesN/AN/ALandlocked Country0.0020.003Landlocked Country with Low Development-0.003-0.002The model indicates that foreign assistance actually becomes detrimental to growth in situations where there is genocide or politicide in low development nations, as predicted. I attribute this to the fact that resources are typically controlled by the dominant party in genocidal conflicts, and it is likely that aid dollars are siphoned off and used for their own benefit instead of productive and efficient activities. extremist conflict eliminates entirely the impact aid has on the economy, resulting a net effect of about zero. I argue that this is the case because the institutions required to effectively utilize foreign assistance are in jeopardy during a major transfer of power, reducing their ability to act efficiently and distribute aid dollars tally to the countrys best interests. Interestingly, ethnic conflict actually increases the effectiveness of aid. This finding is consistent with Easterlys study of ethnic fractionalization and its impact on economic growth.In landlocked countries, aid is particularly effective, tripling the extent to which it impacts economic growth. As Sachs and Warner pointed out, landlocked countries are limited in their ability to engage in global trade. Thus, it seems reasonable that foreign aid positively impacts growth in these areas since their capacity to engage in trade is restricted. However, in low-development countries that are landlocked, this relationship no longer holds. This indicates that whatever benefits aid has in land locked countries is reversed in low-development countries, possibly due to poor institutional quality, corruption, or other factors.As for other variables besides foreign aid, the model shows the effect of foreign direct investment (FDI) on economic growth is surprisingly small an increase of only 0.00003% in GDP for every $1 million US invested. In contrast, foreign aid boosts GDP by 0.001% with the same amount of money. This indicates that foreign aid has a substantially greater impact on growth than foreign direct investment, all else equal. According to the model, being open to trade seems to be a much more effective strategy in growing the economy, even more so than foreign aid and FDI. It is important to note, however, that since openness to trade is measured as a share of GDP, the impact is not directly comparable that of foreign aid or FDI, since economies included in this study vary greatly in size.To quantify how quickly foreign aid impacts the economic growth of a country , I calculate the median lag as outlined by Davies and Quinlivian (2006).30This measure estimates how quickly half of the impact of foreign assistance is felt, and is calculated as followsMedian Lag = = 0.477 (4)A median lag of 0.477 indicates that in approximately 5.7 months, half of the entire impact of foreign aid on GDP growth will be realized. Half of the remaining impact is then felt in another 5.7 months, and so on, as the cumulative impact of the aid asymptotically approaches 100%. This phenomenon is illustrated in Chart 1 below.Graph 1 Cumulative Impact of Foreign Aid on GrowthThe median lag indicates that aid can quickly impact an economy, but for a relatively short amount of time. After only two years of circulation in the recipient economy, over 95% of the total impact of foreign aid is experienced.5. Conclusions and Suggestions for Future ResearchThe purpose of this analysis was to determine the effects of development assistance on economic growth. The model developed i n this paper provides evidence supporting the contention that foreign aid positively impacts economic growth in the developing world. Therefore, it is not in the interest of developed countries and international bodies to discontinue aid programs. Moreover, as Gunning (2004) points out, it would be extremely difficult for a donor country to stop aid since it would be seen by both the domestic and foreign populations as punishing an already poor country.31The model also shows, however, that the effects of aid on economic growth are modest, and buying economic growth through foreign aid would be incredibly inefficient and expensive. For instance, using foreign aid alone to increase GDP by 1% in a country would require a foreign aid package of approximately $1 billion US. With almost 120 countries identified as low- and medium-development, spurring economic growth in developing world to suitable levels would be an enormous expenditure. This also assumes that the negative effects of co nflict and geography shown to be significant in the model do not apply, and ignores the potential problems of aid dependence, corruption, and bureaucratic erosion that research has associated with high levels of foreign aid.The aforementioned studies by Burnside and Dollar (1997) and others have shown aid to be more effective in sound economic policy environments. Thus, donor governments and multilateral institutions should continue to push economic reforms and trade liberalization on recipient governments. Not only will this improve the effectiveness of foreign aid according to these studies, but it will also result in less aid being required.The armed conflict dummies indicate, with the exception of ethnic conflict, that state failure and political instability reverse the positive effect of aid, even making it detrimental to economic growth in some cases. Therefore, donor governments should be aware of the political situations in recipient countries, and work with international bo dies to ensure as much stability as possible. Further, since geography is essentially fixed, foreign aid donations to landlocked countries should be designed to facilitate improvements in transportation infrastructures, which increase their capacity to engage in trade.Future research should further explore the role of sound economic policies and good presidency in aid effectiveness. Scholars should also explore other ways of quantifying climate, tropical geography, and governance to provide for additional testing of potential impacts on the effectiveness of foreign aid. Finally, future study of foreign aid should also investigate its effects on economic development, instead of growth. Doing so will shed light on the question of whether aid actually improves the quality of life in lesser developed countries.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.